Microeconomics For Dummies
Book image
Explore Book Buy On Amazon

Economists distinguish between the long- and short-run positions of a firm. They do so because a firm can find itself, in the short run, in a number of positions where it is constrained.

It can't fully react to change immediately and therefore makes slightly different decisions than it would if there were no constraints — in other words, different than it would in the long run if it were fully capable of reacting to whatever change (pricing, technological, demand, and so on) was taking place.

Economists want to be more precise about what the terms long run and short run mean, without specifying a particular time interval (for example, a month) that will be different for firms in different industries. For example, finding an exploitable oil deposit may take longer than writing a couple lines of code.

The definition economists use is conceptually simple: In the long run, the firm is able to change its use of all factors of production — labor, capital, and land. In the short run, the firm is not able to do that; it's limited to imperfect adjustment, usually of only one factor, often labor.

As an example, imagine that a firm employs ten people to do a job working on ten machines. And suppose the wage it pays its workers has become more expensive, so that the firm would be better off employing only eight machines and eight people. But the lease for the machines is not up until the end of the year, whereas it can lay off workers at any time:

  • In the short run: The firm adjusts its use of labor without adjusting its use of capital or machinery — having nine people operate the ten machines. Over this short-run period, the firm isn't operating at its most effective use of resources.

  • In the long run: After the firm negotiates a new lease, it can operate even more cheaply. Assuming profit maximization is its aim, it moves towards doing so.

Microeconomists express this situation by looking at costs in the short and long run. To an economist, any short-run average total cost (SRATC) curve must be by definition less elastic — that is, less responsive to price — than a long-run average total cost (LRATC) curve.

Therefore, in a diagram, a SRATC curve is steeper, reflecting the lower ability to adjust in the short run (as costs go up, output doesn't change as much as in the long run). The LRATC is always less than or equal to the SRATC at any given output level, reflecting the fact that the firm can use its inputs more efficiently in the long run than in the short run.

The figure illustrates this condition. Remember that a short-run marginal cost curve goes through the minimum of each of the SRATC curves, and the long-run marginal cost (LRMC) is more elastic — price and cost responsive — than in the short run.

Costs in the short and long run.
Costs in the short and long run.

About This Article

This article is from the book:

About the book authors:

Lynne Pepall, PhD, is a professor of economics at Tufts University. She has taught microeconomics at both graduate and undergraduate levels since 1987.

Peter Antonioni is a senior teaching fellow at the Department of Management Science and Innovation, University College, London, and coauthor of Economics For Dummies, 2nd UK Edition.

Manzur Rashid, PhD, is a lecturer at New College of the Humanities, where he covers second-year micro- and macroeconomics.

This article can be found in the category: